Lapas attēli
PDF
ePub
[merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][ocr errors][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small]

Reading left to right, the integrals measure the net benefits of the personal subscribers, the potential subscribers, and the perusers, respectively.

[merged small][ocr errors][merged small][ocr errors][merged small][merged small][subsumed]

Here, without a library subscription, the only readers are those with personal subscriptions. Finally,

[blocks in formation]

Thus, the personal subscribers contribute nothing to WP, and the perusers are willing to pay their full benefit, net of inconvenience, B - T. However, the potential subscribers add only the difference

- T between their evaluations of the library inconvenience and the money cost of a personal subscription.

Ps

Using the willingness to pay concept, we can identify the libraries which are just indifferent to acquiring the journal. Such marginal libraries will be denoted by the index m*, with

[blocks in formation]

For convenience, we take m to be a scalar index defined so that the WP function is increasing in m. (In Appendix 2 we show how to arrive.

at our results with a mathematically more satisfying representation of multidimensionally differentiated libraries.) Letting f(m) be the number of population groups with characteristic m,

[merged small][merged small][merged small][ocr errors][merged small][merged small][merged small]

Denoting by N° the total number of personal subscribers, publisher profits are

(6)

=

π

PsNS + P1N2

- C(NS + N2).

Total social welfare generated by the journal in question, given by the sum of producer's surplus and consumers' surplus,5 is denoted by W = V + π, where

[merged small][merged small][merged small][ocr errors][merged small][subsumed][merged small][merged small]

PS

Now, we can turn to the choice of Ps and PL which maximizes W subject to the constraint that > 0. Forming the Lagrangian,

[ocr errors]

L = W + Xπ = V + (x+1)π, we investigate the necessary first order conditions for positive optimal prices:

[merged small][merged small][ocr errors][ocr errors][merged small][merged small][merged small][ocr errors][merged small][ocr errors][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][ocr errors][merged small][merged small][ocr errors][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small]

However, because of the definitions of m* and WP, (3) and (4), the second term is zero and we are left with this familiar version of Roy's Law6

[merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][ocr errors][merged small][merged small][ocr errors]

Routine differentiation of the profit function (6) gives this solution to the simultaneous equations of (8), where c denotes the marginal cost C' (NS+NL):

[blocks in formation]

Here, subscripts S and L denote partial derivatives with respect to Ps and PL. Of course (11) is the standard Ramsey rule for optimal deviations of prices from marginal costs under the nonnegative profit constraint. If the cross demand partials are zero, then (11) reduces to the familiar inverse elasticity rule. In the present form, (11) is not very illuminating. A more useful formulation can be derived by substituting into it detailed relationships among the partial derivatives of demand extracted from the underlying model.

[merged small][merged small][ocr errors][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][ocr errors][merged small][merged small][merged small][ocr errors][ocr errors][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][ocr errors][merged small][ocr errors][ocr errors][ocr errors][merged small]

Note that > 0, by construction, so that (12) and (13) imply that

[ocr errors]

N<0. Turning back to the definition of WP in (3), we calculate

[merged small][merged small][ocr errors][merged small][merged small][merged small]

This is just the number of potential subscribers who frequent each

marginal library. Together, (12), (13), and (14) yield

[blocks in formation]

The number of personal subscribers in a population, m, with a subscribing library is

[merged small][merged small][merged small][ocr errors][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][ocr errors][subsumed][merged small][ocr errors][merged small][merged small][merged small]

with respect to PL, which affects only the set of subscribing libraries,

[merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][ocr errors][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small]

Now, together with (15) and (12), (19) reveals that

(20)

N = N = PNS (m)N≥ 0.

The relationships in (20) are both surprising and useful. Personal and library subscriptions are gross substitutes, provided there are potential subscribers in the marginal libraries.9 Despite the fact that the demand for library subscriptions is determined by the simultaneous collective decisions of many population groups, while N results from the individual decisions of the agents, the Slutsky symmetry of the demand cross-partials (with no income effects) is preserved.

NS

It remains only to investigate the behavior of N° with respect to changes in Ps. Working from (18),

[merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][ocr errors][subsumed][ocr errors][merged small][subsumed]

We denote by NS the negative terms in the brackets which represent the

S

derivative of N° with respect to pc, holding constant the set of subscribing libraries. Using (13), (14), and (19), we have

[blocks in formation]
« iepriekšējāTurpināt »