Lapas attēli
PDF
ePub

that system will at once avoid the evils of a restricted moneysupply, secure an approximate par of exchange between gold countries and silver countries, and promote stability of value in the money of the commercial world. They are not inflationists, although, in accordance with their general views regarding the importance of the status, and the evils of disturbing the existing structure of industrial society, they strongly deprecate contraction.

Such are the elements which compose what I have ventured to call the silver party, though there has never been, in truth, any organized party which brought the three classes together. As yet no issue has arisen which has put all these people upon one side.

The free-coinage party, with us, derive a certain strength beyond that warranted by their numbers or character. Their grievance is the ill-considered and unwarrantable demonetization of silver by Congress in 1873. To the average free-silver advocate this Act cannot be explained away; though I do not believe that any fraud was therein committed or intended. The effect of such Act was scarcely apprehended at the time. Some committeeman, or some few committeemen, ran the pen through "the dollar of our fathers," and the thing was done. Few Congressmen outside the committee knew that any vital change was impending.

So completely without observation was this measure passed that it was not for a year or two that the fact of demonetization was popularly known. Then, indeed, public interest in the subject became aroused. The price of silver, which had started out of line on the announcement of the demonetization of the metal by Germany (1873), began to tumble rapidly as that purpose was accomplished, and as the French demand for coinage was more and more checked. The mean annual rate of exchange by weight of silver had been 151⁄2 to one ounce of gold. In 1873 it changed to 15.92; in 1874, to 16.17; in 1875, to 16.58; in 1876, to 17.84, and in July of the latter year to

20.17.

In the session of 1877-8 Congress passed a Bill remonetizing the silver dollar and providing that two million dollars' worth of silver bullion as a minimum, four million dollars' worth as a maximum, should be purchased monthly by the Secretary of the Treasury and coined into dollars of 4121⁄2 grains; and also providing for the calling of an International Monetary Conference. This Bill was vetoed by President Hayes, but was promptly passed over the veto.

From the point of view of a bimetallist, it is to be said of this Bill, that the rehabilitation of the silver dollar was eminently right and just. But the provision for monthly coinage was a most unwise one, so far as the interests of international bimetallists were concerned, and was so regarded in this country and in Europe. The objections to this measure were twofold. First, the ratio between gold and silver in the coinage of the United States-16:1-was not coincident with that of the Latin Union and some countries outside of that league, viz., 15%: 1. In thus coining at a different ratio, this country was not pulling with France and her monetary allies, but, in some degree, away from them. Besides this, the moral effect was to induce grave skepticism as to our motives. The members of the Latin Union might well say: "It is we who have to bear all the brunt; for all the bullion will, under free coinage come to us; for who is going to have silver coined in the United States, where it takes 16 ounces to purchase one ounce of gold, when in Europe he can purchase for 151⁄2 ounces?" On the other hand, if we were to go to the French ratio, upon condition of general free coinage, our continuing to coin several millions a month, at our own ratio, was pure folly. All the dollars so coined would have to be melted and recoined at much expense.

The second reason against the coinage of silver in 1878 was still stronger. By purchasing silver then, we were certain to diminish the pressure upon the European States to undertake

measures for the rehabilitation of that metal. To them our coinage under the Act of February 28, 1878, was a gratuitous gift. We put our fingers into the door and took the squeezing which of right belonged to them. Under these circumstances it is not strange that the Monetary Conference initiated by that Act failed to do anything for silver.

The lapse of time, the large experience of gold monometallism, has not reconciled the world to the demonetization of silver. I believe our people would be practically unanimous in favor of a treaty by which England, France, and the United States, or Germany, France, and the United States, should enter into a monetary alliance, on terms similar to those of the Latin Union. In England there is a steady, though not rapid, movement of public opinion in the same direction.

But we cannot " go it alone," as many of our people propose The Act of 1890 has enormously increased the perils of our situation. The purchase of 54,000,000 ounces of silver bullion a year is a very serious matter. It has given tremendous impetus to the dangerous movement upon which we entered in 1878. It is apparently fast sweeping us to the gulf of silver monometallism. From this there is no escape, except through the concurrence of European nations in setting up a genuine bimetallic system, or through the prompt repeal of this objectionable law. The former way of escape is not likely to be opened to us. It remains to be seen whether the people of the United States have political virtue enough to rescue themselves, their public faith, and their commercial credit from a most compromising and perilous position, to that end defying alike mistaken opinion and the clamors and threats of selfish interests.

THE REFERENDUM. ALBERT RAMALHO.

Translated and Condensed for THE LITERARY DIGEST from a Paper in Revue Générale d'Administration, Paris, February.

[ocr errors]

O much has been written about the institution of the Referendum, à propos of the attempt to introduce it into Belgium, that many think it a new thing in the world. This is far from being the case. The Referendum existed at Athens and in the republics of the Middle Ages. At Rome the people made the laws, and such is still the case in certain Swiss cantons. In other cantons the people ratify only. It is asked, then, are we inferior to the contemporaries of Demosthenes, to the ancient Romans, to the Italians of the thirteenth century, to the Swiss people?

Certainly not. But the twenty thousand citizens of Athens, of whom about five thousand only ratified the laws and the decrees of the Senate, in the temple of Bacchus, owned four hundred thousand slaves, without political, or even civil, rights, and these slaves looked after the private affairs of Athenian citizens. The most of the free families numbered, or had numbered, among their members senators, archons, magistrates, commanders of galleys. The Athenians were, in reality, a people of functionaries. Below these lived, in the fields or the workshops, another people without history, exclusively occupied with servile labor, and leaving the former at liberty to devote themselves to the noble work of attending to public interests.

It was the same or even more so in Rome, where the noble or rich classes alone carried on public affairs.

The Italian republics of the Middle Ages applied the Referendum to declarations of war and treaties of peace. In the matter of slavery, however, the situation was nearly the same as in the republics of antiquity. Moreover, the Referendum ceased to exist when the interests of the State became more complicated and ceased to be circumscribed by the limit of the needs of a city.

As to Switzerland, it is composed of cantons that are rich (notwithstanding the poverty of some of them), because they have few needs. To protect a neutrality guaranteed by solemn

[ocr errors]

treaties, militia only is necessary. The taxes are light, and there is no antagonism, either of classes or of great industrial combinations. The majority of the country is composed of small owners of real estate. Switzerland has a privileged situation, which puts the Confederation outside of European conflagrations. This state of things explains, if it does not justify, the Referendum.

In the absence of these favorable conditions, the Referendum is a dangerous institution, the practical use of which would be nearly impossible in most cases. Among modern nations there is a tendency, more and more marked, to group themselves into vast agglomerations of human beings united by a community of language, of institutions, of historical traditions, and which seem less and less disposed to be divided into small cities. In the latter there may be more happiness, but not that feeling of security which gives strength and which has become the most urgent need of contemporary Europe.

[ocr errors]

The Future of International Arbitration. Every lover of humanity hopes that arbitration will eventually take the place of war in settling differences between nations, and everything bearing on this subject written by acute thinkers is worthy of careful consideration. The French Academy of Moral and Political Sciences has eulogized in its section of Legislation and awarded a prize to a work written by Michel Revon, Doctor of Laws, on "International Arbitration." Doctor Revon is of the opinion that in ten years either a general war will have turned Europe upside down or militarism will be powerless. In this alternative he does not hesitate to declare that war, which formerly had a good reason for existing, has such no longer, and that arbitration, which is making its way more and more, will become in the near future the law. While he claims that arbitration is a reform absolutely necessary and quite possible to bring about, he admits its extreme difficulty. For this reason, after having carefully collected all the facts, after analyzing, classifying, and criticising all the projects heretofore proposed, he puts forward a detailed scheme for international arbitration, not a definitive, perfect, absolute scheme. but founded on considerations very likely to take place in a future, more or less near. Besides considering international arbitration from the triple point of view, of its organization, its competency, and its procedure, he gives a summary of the consequences which will follow such a reform, in moral progress, in economic progress, and especially in juridical progress, that is, by the definite establishment of a state of law, of a federative system, and of peace, not perpetual, but approaching more and more that end so ardently to be desired.Nouvelle Revue Historique de Droit Français et Etranger, Paris, February.

VERY

SOCIOLOGICAL.

SCHOOL STATISTICS AND MORALS.
COMMISSIONER W. T. HARRIS.

Condensed for THE LITERARY DIGEST from a Paper in
School Review, Cornell University, April.

VERY justly do theologians claim that religious education is the foundation of the institutions of civilization. But it does not necessarily follow that the school should be an appanage of the Church, or that anything but secular education should be attempted in it.

I think that the most scientific student of social science will admit that the school is no substitute for the Church, and that a nation may possibly exist without a school, but that no nation can exist without a Church. Christianity is for ever narrowing the circle of superstition and increasing the realm of enlightenment.

Right here comes in the first appeal to statistics, and the first attack and defense of the school on the line of moral

influence. It is supposed on the one hand that purely secular instruction in ideas and habits must be anti-religious and, consequently, tend towards vice and crime. On the other hand it is claimed that purely secular instruction reinforces religion, and exerts an influence repressive of vice and crime. Statistics are collated to show that the majority of criminals in our jails have attended school for a longer or shorter period. Statistics are likewise quoted to show that those States which have the oldest and most efficient school systems have the largest number of criminals in their jails and state-prisons. Assertions are made that education merely changes the character of the crime, for example from robbery and theft, the crimes of the illiterate, to forgery and embezzlement or breach of trust, the crimes of those who have had school education. In the collation of statistics made on the census-returns of 1870, by E. D. Mansfield, the returns from prisons and jails of seventeen States, fourteen of which were Western or Middle States, gave an aggregate of 110,538 prisoners, of whom 27,581, or, almost twenty-five per cent., were illiterate or not able to write.

This fact looked serious enough to challenge the good influence claimed for the schools. If school education is adverse to crime, why should not the statistics show that a majority of the prisoners are illiterate ?

At this point the question was modified so as to ask whether a given number of illiterates furnished as many criminals as the same number of persons who could read and write.

In the seventeen States which furnished the twenty-five per cent. of illiterate criminals, according to the census of 1870, four per cent. of the population furnished this twenty-five per cent., and the ninety-six per cent. who could read and write furnished only seventy-five per cent. The illiterates furnished more than six times their quota, while those who could read and write furnished one-fifth less than their quota, and the ratio was as one to eight. A thousand illiterates on an average furnished eight times as many prisoners as the same number who could read and write.

The main point in the interpretation of criminal statistics is to consider the ratio between the number of criminals furnnished by a given number of illiterates as compared with a like number who can read and write.

The question of the prevention and cure of crime is a very complicated one, having many coöperating causes besides that of defect of schooling. But that schooling is a very powerful influence is made probable by these statistics, and it is made certain by considering its nature.

To those who have objected to secular education as tending to fill our jails with educated criminals, the defenders of the schools have pointed significantly to the statistics of religious education among criminals. For instance, in the Detroit jail, in twenty-five years, 37,089 were reported as having religious training, against 2,249 who had had none. In the reports from two hundred jails in the United States with about 55,000 prisoners last year, over one-half reported religious training of prisoners.

The neophyte in statistics would say that the ninety-two per cent. of criminals in Detroit who had received religious instruction, made a bad showing for religious education. But he has omitted his denominator like the bad arithmeticians who have been decrying public education, and comparing numerators without a glance at their denominators.

The religious statistics would read, when the denominators are supplied, somewhat as follows: The ninety-two per cent. of criminals who have had some religious instruction have been furnished by the ninety-eight or ninety-nine per cent. of the whole population who have been under religious instruction, while the eight per cent. without previous religious teaching represent the one or two per cent. of their class. And none of the criminals came there through religious teaching, but because they neglected its counsels.

The attack on school education as increasing the number of

criminals, has brought forward a new phase of the question. Massachusetts, it was said, committed to its jails 8,761 persons in 1850, while in 1885 it committed 26,651, or nearly three times as many. In 1850 less than nine persons in one thousand in 1885, nearly fourteen. This evidently demanded a qualitative inquiry: What crimes are on the increase? Mr. David C. Torrey classified them under two heads, and found that the crimes against person and property were, from 1865 to 1870, one to 301 inhabitants, while from 1880 to 1885 they were one to 436—thus showing a decrease in serious crimes of forty-four per cent. The second heading was for crimes against order and decency, and these had increased largely, and Mr. Torrey found that they were mostly cases of drunken

ness.

This showing completely turned the tables on that class of sensational or emotional writers who deal with what I call hypnotical statistics. While person and property have become safer in twenty-five years, drunkenness is not nearly so safe; the prisons and jails are crowded with intemperate people, who were formerly allowed to go unmolested.

Of the secular virtues, justice is particularly concerned in this matter of crime. It has two phases, honesty and truthspeaking, and they are particularly cultivated in the schools. Temperance is a virtue which the school helps to some extent. Prudence or Providence is the special virtue of thrift, and the school nurtures this by increasing intelligence and skill in productive industry.

Now

TRADE-UNIONS AND THE LAW.
Condensed for THE LITERARY DIGEST from a Paper in
Yale Review, Boston, February.

that the excitement connected with the labor crisis of 1892 has passed away, and the antipathies engendered by such a strife have probably cooled down, it seems a fitting time to consider the problem of preventing similar disturbances in the future. It certainly would seem to be the part of wisdom to take measures to forestall occurrences such as have disgraced our civilization in '77, '86, and '92, rather than wait until the emergency arises, and then allow it to be dealt with in a more or less haphazard manner, either by the local officials in whose province the disturbances happen to occur, or by the State militia.

The fact seems to be often lost sight of that crime committed in connection with disputes about wages or hours of labor, is something very different from that committed by the so-called criminal classes. The motives of the perpetrators are different, the occasions which give rise to them are different, and we are not likely to be successful in dealing with them until we face this fact, and establish either special legislation or special agencies to deal with these special cases. The ordinary county sheriff is as helpless in dealing with strikers as is the ordinary policeman in dealing with college students.

or not, is at any rate bound to exist, and which even stringent laws have found it impossible to put down. It is an institution, moreover, whose members, otherwise peaceable and lawabiding, are liable, at times, to commit violence and crime, in obedience, as they suppose, to the interest of the institution. Yet the policy of our Government is to leave it entirely to itself until matters have gone so far that crime has actually been committed, and that the evil can no longer be prevented, but at the most avenged.

The United States Government has passed a law with regard to international unions which has not resulted in much as yet, but which may be taken as indicating the possible direction of future legislation.

According to the Act of June 29, 1886, national trade-unions may be incorporated under the laws of the United States, by complying with very simple rules. Congress might easily go a little further and provide more in detail, as has been done by the English Trade-Union Act, just what the responsibilities and rights of the union should be.

If the trade-union is recognized as an institution which the United States may fitly incorporate, the Government owes it to the members of the institution to protect them against malfeasance on the part of their leaders; no less does it owe it to the public to protect it against outrages on the part of the union. The union itself, for instance, might be made pecuniarily responsible for damages done by its officers, in the same way in which corporations are pecuniarily responsible to people who may be injured by them. On the other hand, the union itself should not only be protected against abuses of power on the part of its officers, but should also be secured against interference, as long as its members remain within the law.

It is not to be supposed that all of the evils connected with trade-unions can be done away with by simple legislation, but it does not seem over sanguine to believe that as much might be done as has been done in correcting the abuses of corporations. These abuses have not been done away with, and it is still possible for the managers of great companies to use them for their own ends, to the detriment both of the public and of the shareholders. There is no doubt, however, that such an abuse of power is much more difficult now than it was twenty years ago. Similar legislation with regard to trade-unions would probably result in a similar state of things. Whether this legislation could be performed by Congress or by the States, it is not easy to say.

A

THE PULPIT AND THE LIQUOR TRAFFIC.
CHARLES A. PAYNE, D.D., LL.D.
Condensed for THE LITERARY DIGEST from a Paper in
Christian Thought, New York, April.

CHAIN of linked logic as strong as that which binds the universe together, binds our subject upon the conscience of the Church and the pulpit.

I. The first link in the chain is the incontrovertible fact that the liquor traffic is the greatest curse of Christendom, and a stupendous obstacle in the way of the Christian Church.

II. Link second. This greatest enemy of man and deadly foe of Christ's Kingdom will be conquered only by the agency of the Christian Church. It is vain to expect the Devil to strike. down his strongest ally. The world expects and awaits the

The first thing to be remembered is that labor organizations are very old and a very wide-spread institutions. In fact, it is altogether probable that they may be regarded as one of the inherited institutions of the Aryan race. Our modern unions show in many instances elements of human nature quite similar to those that determined the character of the medieval guilds and of the East Indian castes. We see the same tendency to make trade hereditary, the same desire for exclusiveness, the same intolerance towards those who are outside of the pale. Along-leadership of the Church in this as in all other moral reforms. side of these defects, however, we see also the element of mutual help, a standard of honor, an aim to keep up the technical skill of the craft, and an effort to maintain the standard of living, which are altogether very useful features.

If these tendencies of our labor organizations are so general as to be almost innate, it is obvious that any legislation will be futile which considers them as accidental and takes no account of them. The facts then are these: Here is an institution which, whether its good features outbalance its bad ones

III. The third link is the fact that the Church can cope successfully with the liquor traffic only when the Church forces are thoroughly massed. A united foe, a divided Church. This sentence tells the story of our long defeat,

There is no sadder sight on earth than to see the liquor forces rally around a common standard, irrespective of party or creed or personal relations, while the temperance forces are hotly contending about measures and methods, and, for the most part, practically aiding the combined enemy. Can there

be any intelligent questioning of the fact that the duty of the hour is to unite all the forces that acknowledge loyalty to Christ, and march in soldierly order and serried ranks against the common foe?

The toleration of the liquor traffic is the greatest anachronism of the Nineteenth Century, the greatest crime of Christendom, the greatest shame of the Christian Church. Thirteen millions of communicants of the Protestant Christian Church, in this Christian Nation, and this traffic of Hell unchecked. Thirteen million Christian men and women in Protestantism and six million more in the Catholic communion, all helpless and palsied in the presence of this oligarchy of Satan. Nineteen million professing Christians and a hundred thousand Christian ministers, and the saloon has more power in the politics of this country than all the Churches, all the ministers, all the membership, all the colleges and schools of the Nation combined. Could not these millions of Christian people outlaw the liquor traffic if they would? Could they not stop the legal manufacture and sale of intoxicating beverages if they would? Could they not prevent the United States Government and every State from having any further complicity with this iniquity by licensing or legalizing it in any form if they would? Beyond question, all this is far within the power and province of the Christian Church.

IV. The pulpit is the legitimate and divinely ordained agency to mass the forces of the Christian Church, and to lead them on to victory in this holy crusade against the liquor traffic.

for this very convenient doctrine of unprincipled politicians who do not like to face the pulpit's opposition. But since the gravest moral questions are involved in the politics of a country like our own, it is treason to truth and to God to demand the silence of the pulpit on these questions.

As a minister, the pastor should be non-partisan, but not non-Christian. But non-partisanship by no means requires the pulpit to be silent on all political questions. On the contrary, the silence of a public man like the minister is rightly construed as decidedly partisan, and is often the most effective form of carrying out party measures.

But are we not in danger of falling into error concerning the relations and duty of the pulpit to political organizations and measures? What law of God, what principle of Christianity, what reasonable requirement of man, demands the silence of the pulpit concerning any man or body of men, any society, or corporation, or organization, whose avowed principles and open conduct vitally affect the interests of society? And what command of Christ, or what principle of ethics, exempts the organization called a political party from the honest consideration, or, if need be, the denunciation of the Christian pulpit? Indeed, the political party, because it makes its appeals for popular support, is more than other organizations the legitimate subject of pulpit discussion.

V. A united pulpit will soon bring a united Church. The Christian forces will be massed, and the legalized traffic in intoxicating drink will be overthrown,

If it be said, that the pulpit should preach temperance but leave unrebuked the traffic; reform the drunkard, but spare EDUCATION, LITERATURE, ART.

the drunkard-maker, then you ask the pulpit to belittle its own work in the eyes of all manly men by openly confessing its puerility and pusillanimity. Since the saloon is the central source of the crimes and curses and woes of mankind, if the pulpit cannot, or will not antagonize this evil, it may as well abandon its calling and cease its high pretensions.

But how shall this duty be performed? The pulpit must keep before the people the true standard of total abstinence for the individual and total legal prohibition for the traffic.

Undoubtedly, the one difficult aspect in the treatment of the case is the political aspect. We are told by men who think themselves honest that this whole question of temperance and the liquor traffic should be kept out of politics. Very good; but we may as well be told that sin should be kept out of the world. The disagreeable fact is that sin is in the world. The equally resistless fact is that the liquor traffic is in politics, and it is there of its own volition. It is common to charge its presence in politics upon temperance reformers, but this is a mistake. The liquor oligarchy put this question into politics. It did this most naturally, and, considering its own interests only, most wisely.

The liquor question is in politics, and can never be gotten out of politics until the ministry and the Church unite to put it out. And they will never put it out by pious talk nor fervent prayer. In this issue, forced upon us by the enemy, votes, and votes only, give the ultimate decision. The liquor question will never be out of politics until forced out by the ballots of free men, emancipated from party domination.

In order to do this the pulpit has a delicate and difficult, but necessary, duty to perform. Men calling themselves Christians must be made to see that there is no evil of society greater than the saloon, and no duty greater than the destruction of the saloon; that the saloon must be outlawed; that it cannot be outlawed until a majority of voters demand it, and that this necessary majority can never be secured while men slavishly follow the dictum of party managers who recruit the saloon

vote.

But we are told that the pulpit must not meddle with politics. By whose authority, and in whose interest is this saying so flippantly bandied about? Surely the Bible is not sponsor

[blocks in formation]

mainly compiled from material in various foreign magazinearticles. In one of them it states that, according to the Deutsche Rundschau:

"When Germany had won the great victories of 1870, the question was asked in all lands what might be the cause of this success, and the German public school was mentioned as the main factor in the success.'

"To this statement no one will seriously object, but most people will be amused when they hear the sentence which follows: At once all nations set about reforming their schools for the people.'

However, the German author uses the argument in order to say, that if popular education is to continue as it has begun, then popular libraries must be increased both as to numbers and usefulness. He argues that even the conservative elements in England recognize that persons whose education has been enlarged by public libraries are of quicker perceptions and more rapid understanding than those not educated thus. He thinks that the effect of public-library reading will largely affect the results of the coming wars."

The next series concerns itself mainly with statistics to show "what people read." It groups these statistics concerning libraries in different parts of the world, and the result reveals the fact that the reading public is very much the same everywhere.

[blocks in formation]

belong to the class fiction, has been only too often emphasized and looked upon with horror, but it ought not to surprise us. After the labors of the day, people, as a rule, do not sit down to study heavy, scholarly writings. They ask for a lively and quickening book, a good novel, a biography, a record of travels, or a review. This is natural and right. Nobody denies that people are religious and that they conduct themselves after a reasonable and practical philosophy. The manner, however, in which religion and philosophy is presented to the people is unpopular because it tires them. People prefer the works of the great popular writers because they contain both experience and the greatest thoughts popularized. It may safely be said that sensational literature is read only where depraved taste rules, or where nothing better can be had. The English and American public library proves that public reading can be regulated. Reports from St. Louis show how social and ethical works are on the increase. Certain works maintain a definite rate on the list of outloans. Such are some of Dickens's, Scott's, Uncle Tom's Cabin,' Ben Hur,' 'Les Miserables,' 'Vanity Fair,' Marble Faun,' etc. The Boston Public Library published in 1867 the following comparative list of authors according to their popularity with readers: Cooper read 5,460 times against Dickens 4,000, Marryat 3,730, Mrs. Henty 3,380, Scott 2,660, Simms 2,380, Miss Muloch 1,660, Miss Young 1,310. Of youthful writings, Mr. Mayne Reid's and Abbott collections were taken out 4,900-2,220, Franconia books 930, H. C. Andersen 390, Grimm 310. The relative position of poets was as follows: Shakespeare 550, Longfellow 430, Goethe 338, Schiller 262, Kotzebue 220, Tennyson 120. In Bergen, last year, the relative order in which the works of writers were asked for were as follows: Bjórnson, Ibsen, Lie, Kjellanp, Janson, Holberg, Ingemann, Rumohr, Etlar, H. F. Ewald, Bergsón, Andersen, Dodt, Thyregod, Scott, Cooper, Marryat, Dickens, James, Mrs. Stowe, Shakespeare."

R

[ocr errors]

THE RUSSIANS IN ORIENTAL LITERATURE.*
MAJOR-GENERAL W. F. TYRRELL.

Condensed for the THE LITERARY DIGEST from a Paper in
Academy, London, March.

USSIA looks with a Janus face on the Eastern and Western worlds; to the latter she seems the champion of conservative ideas, to the former she appears as the incarnation of progress. St. Petersburg, the throne of the Ak Pádisháh, or Great White Czar, is the new Mecca towards which the faces of Orientals are now turned. Notices, however, of Russia in the literature of the East are not very common, and the British Museum contains no work on that country in any Oriental language. To the Moslem anything beyond the pale of Islam is unworthy of attention. All the ages before the coming of Mohammed are lumped together as the time of ignorance; and the Powers of Europe are styled "The Seven Infidel Kingdoms of the Farang." The earliest reference to Russia is in the geography of Al Más'údi, entitled "Meadows of Gold and Mines of Silver," compiled towards the end of the tenth century A. D. He describes the Empire of the Khazars (the "Avars" of Gibbon), whose chief city was the Ihl on the Volga. They are now shrunk to an insignificant tribe on the shores of

Khazars, who are reinforced by giants, caught roosting in the trees of the northern forests, and tamed in chains. In the end the Russians are beaten and have to pay a tribute of animals' skins. Nizami calls the Russians Gurba chashm," blue-eyed (lit. cat-eyed), black (karâ) being the epithet used to describe their favorite type of beauty. The fabulous stories of the wars of Alexander the Great with the Russians are accepted as authentic by Moslems and confer quite as much prestige on the Moscovites as do their present power and position. Mohammedans say "Rúm and Rús are old nations; but whoever heard of England or Germany until this present day?" Another Arab geographer, Sharif al Idrisi, describes ar Rússúja at length in his Book. for the Solace of the Enquirer into the Knowledge of the Universe," compiled for his patron, Roger, the Norman King of Sicily, about 1150 A. D. He is followed in most respects by Ibn Khalidán and Mohammed Ibn Batúba, the celebrated Arab traveler (about 1350 A. D.) Chaucer a little later says in his "Story of Cambuscan Bold," "At Sara in the lande of Tartarie,

66

There dwelled a king who worried Russie,"

which seems to disprove Mr. Morfill's assertion that the word Russia was not invented until the seventeenth century. The pious Batúta was much puzzled by the shortness of the northern nights, for he had no sooner finished his sunset-prayer than he had to begin that for the dawn. The songs of the Tartar nomads still bewail the fall of the " strong-walled " city, Kazán, and the fate of their hero, Batyr Tora, in the time of Ivan the Terrible. Similar folk-songs lament the loss of the Crimea and the Caucasus. The Russian victories of Peter, the Pádisháh, are related in the celebrated Persian history, "The World-Conquests of Nádor Shah." The Czars here are uniformly called "Sun-crowned Emperors." Previous to 1740 they were styled by the Turks, Karál, the Slavonic for king. Many Russian words are now adopted into Persian. A straw shows which way the wind blows, and the Oriental mind is profoundly impressed by the might of Russia. An irresistible destiny is leading Japhet to dwell in the tents of Shem, and is replacing the civilization of Islam by a system more in accordance with the improved knowledge and increased needs of our own time.

INSTRUCTION IN POLITICAL AND SOCIAL SCIENCES.*

LEON AUCOC.

Translated and Condensed for THE LITERARY DIGEST from a Paper in Annales de l'Ecole Libre des Sciences Politiques, Paris, January-April.

the Caspian Sea, which is still called by the Persians Rahr al SOCIAL and political sciences have of late been grouped

Khazaran. The Russians (Ar-Rús) are recognized by an Arab geographer, who narrates their piratical forays on the shores of the Pontus and on Constantinople. They had 500 ships, each containing 100 men and (about 920 A. D.) traded or ravaged from Spain to the Naphtha country (Baku). He says: "Perhaps those who maintain that the sea of the Khazar is connected with the strait of Constantinople mean by the sea of the Khazar the Mayotis and the Pontus, which is the sea of the Targhiz (Bulgarians and Russians). God knows how this is." He also notices the raids of the Norsemen (about 400 A. H.) whom the Muslims of Spain believed to be a Magian nation, but Al Más'údi supposed to be Russians. The Persian poets-Firdusi in his "Shah Náma" and Nazáma in the "Shikander Náma" -allude to the exploits of the "Prophet-King" Alexander the Great, 'who cleaned the world from the yellow Russians." Seven chapters of Nizami's epic describe the sanguinary conflict between the Emperor of Rúm (Alexander) and the Russian forces under the Kintal (probably Slavonic Káral) of the *From a paper read before the Anglo-Russian Society, London, March 7.

[ocr errors]

together under the name Social Sciences, a designation which makes it difficult to determine their boundaries. The question as to what place instruction in social and political sciences ought to occupy in higher instruction has been settled in many of the countries of Europe and in the United States in various ways.

The question was discussed at the International Congress of Higher and Secondary Instruction, held at Paris in 1889, the year of the Universal Exposition.

"

Mr. Boutmy made to the Congress a report, in which he attributed the difficulties in the solution of the problem to two causes: one, to the fact that the expression "economic and social sciences has not acquired a well-defined meaning, and that, as a consequence of the general movement of ideas, there is a tendency to include in those sciences everything which is connected with the constitution and development of human societies; the other, that the programmes of higher instruction have in certain countries a suppleness which they * A paper read before the French Academy of Moral and Political Sciences.

« iepriekšējāTurpināt »